Posts tagged ‘enron’

Performance Measures and Incentives, Part 1: Lessons From A Famous Corporate Implosion

Part of a Series:  Organizational Design, Behavior, and Change

To understand why organizations grow senescent, get fat, and fail – whether they be public or private – there is probably no topic more important than performance measures and incentives.  Many readers will know that I have spent 25 years working with government agencies in a company that privately operates public recreation facilities.  Not infrequently I have had my managers, in frustration over something our agency partners have done or not done, complain that the folks they are working with in the government are “bad” people.  More generally this is a common refrain of government critics, that state agencies are full of “bad” people.  I always disagree with them.

The people that the government hires are no different on average than the people hired in private industry.  Sure, there is some self-selection as people may migrate to institutions they trust more than others or to work cultures they find more appealing, but this is true as well among private entities (e.g. choosing to work at a startup vs Exxon).  My strong belief, from theory and long experience, is that when government employees appear to act “badly” or irrationally, it is not because they are (or began as) bad people but because they are working in an organization with terrible incentives and a counter-productive performance management system.  This is not unique to government organizations – many or most of the great failures of once-proud private companies have come about due to issues with incentives.  The difference is that when private organizations go bad, there is a culling by customers and competitors that has no equivalent in the perfect monopoly of government agencies.

I will return to the issue of government incentives in the next post, but I want to reinforce the importance of incentives to organizational failure by discussing one famous private example, a company everyone thinks of as failing due to fraud and malfeasance – ie bad people – but whose downfall was at its core due to bad incentives:  Enron.  In what follows I don’t want to take away from the criminality of various executives.  But I believe the failure at Enron started WAY before the criminality and was rooted in bad incentives.

The story starts with Jeff Skilling coming to Enron to implement the gas bank model he came up with at McKinsey.  Having personally been on this study for a brief time (as a very junior associate), I don’t think there was anything particularly wrong with the strategy.  The problem was perhaps in Jeff himself.   As has been reported many times, he was certainly brilliant, but my guess is that he was likely manic-depressive, and he certainly did not have a very good read on people.  I won’t say he was on the spectrum but had a sort of quasi-autistic inability to understand how people really tick.  He could fall in love with his own intellectual creations, which might be marvelous in theory, but fraught in actual implementation with real people.

Here is my theory – the downfall of Enron can be traced directly to Jeff Skilling’s implementation of what he called “mark-to-market accounting” for new Enron contracts, an academically intriguing idea that met with disaster in the face of real people.  To understand it, we first need to know what he meant by “mark-to-market accounting."

Since the dawn of capitalism, enterprises have struggled with how to provide the proper incentives to their sales force and dealmakers.  The simplest example to reward salespeople with a percentage-of-revenue commission.  It certainly seems logical to reward salespeople for making sales.  But even something so simple quickly becomes fraught when it encounters real human behavior.  The problem is that sales people will chase the easiest sales with the highest discounts, building a book of business that maximizes their commissions but may miss the most profitable sales. The same is true for deal makers, who (if allowed) will pursue the riskiest deals with the highest potential returns, leaving the company on the hook for future potential losses.

And this problem was an order of magnitude worse at Enron, where Skilling implemented a strategy in which traders are tasked with executing complicated long-term deals.  Traders were executing deals as long as 20 years in which natural gas might be bought here and then sold there and then converted to electricity which is sold somewhere else all tied to a capital investment at a certain plant and sale of tax credits to other companies.    Most, meaning pretty much all, companies would account for this by simply reporting the net profits from this deal in each year as they occur.  But what if most of the profit in the deal was 10+ years out?  Should the company, or the individual dealmaker, really have to wait 10 years to be rewarded?  Would the organization even bother pursuing these contracts if that were the case?

Skilling hated this traditional accounting.  Companies are often criticized for not thinking about the long term – how can one reward the organization for selling business 20 years out? He believed strongly that once the deal was signed these gains were all earned and locked in, such that the present value of the contract was essentially earned at signing and should be booked at signing.  Rather than waiting 20 years for the earnings to flow through, Skilling wanted to book the whole profit immediately, crediting both the company and the individual deal-maker with the entire value immediately.  This is what he called mark-to-market.  All the present value of profits from a multi-year contract would be booked when signing the contract.  And the deal maker would be rewarded for a percentage of those profits on signing.  Like much of Skilling’s thinking, this was a theoretically compelling approach.

Mark-to-market was a term well known at the time in the banking and securities world.  It refers to the process of adjusting the book value of investments to their market price.  All well and good – this was something the government was trying to get banks and financial institutions to adopt – so the government was open to approving Enron’s proposal for what was very unusual accounting in the energy world.

The problem for Enron was that they were, by their own admission, doing deals that were unique, that no one else was doing.  So how does one establish a market price?  Not everything was locked in by the contract – profits might depend on commodity prices or cost overruns or interest rates or even the bankruptcy of a counter-party.  Skilling may have called it mark-to-market, but that was effectively impossible. What Enron was really doing could more reasonably be called mark to forecast.  The forecasted revenue and profits for the contract would be recognized immediately on signing.

And now we arrive at the disaster.  Enron had the dealmakers themselves creating the pro formas or forecasts from their deals from which the present value determination was made.  So, what is this forecast going to look like?  The forecasts were going to be hugely optimistic -- the deal is going to make a freaking fortune with little risk, the forecast is going to be a hockey stick upwards.   This does not necessarily even require fraud – every sales person and deal maker who has ever existed is optimistic about their own deals.  And given that these are 20-year forecasts, the valuation of the deal might turn on the price of natural gas 20 years out.  Whose to say that $5 is more or less reasonable than $3?  The net effect is that all the mark-to-market valuations skewed high.

Skilling and Lay seemed mostly blind to this problem.  They did (nominally) create internal agencies that were meant to neutrally review deals and these mark to market valuations.  But these groups got little support from executives, particularly when deal makers seemed to be making so much money for the company (at least on this mark-to-market basis).  Deal makers had become the elite of the organization, virtually unchallengeable even by staff originally tasked with challenging them.  And remember that Lay & Skilling’s prestige and compensation – not to mention the compensation of every manager at Enron given their compensation system -- was largely stock-based, and the stock price was being driven up by the stacking up of these skewed mark-to-market valuations of projects, causing the company to effectively pull forward years of future (potential) earnings into the current year.  Anyone who started challenging project valuations was effectively attacking the entire organization’s compensation.

Enron eventually applied mark-to-market accounting to everything.  Change in tax law?  Take a one-time gain for expected net present value of decades of tax breaks.   Sign a video streaming deal with Blockbuster?  Immediately book profits for 20 years of hypothesized streaming revenue.  Of course, if the assumptions behind a deal were to change for the worse – say a reduction in natural gas prices from those forecast – then there should have been a mark-to-market loss taken on the contract, but that almost never happened. 

This was Skilling’s underlying ethical failure – mark-to-market was his conception, and he was responsible for making sure both halves of the process were implemented:  both taking credit for future gains when contracts were signed but also taking losses for impairments on those future results as they became obvious. I am not sure the mark-to-forecast approach could ever have worked in the real world, but its only chance was to have Skilling create a strong ethics and value structure in the company around rigorous and honest evaluation of current and past marks. And that sure as hell did not happen. If anything, Skilling behaved in the opposite manner, rewarding creativity in evading any loss and eking out new gains from re-marking past projects with rosier assumptions.

Enron’s reported results quickly began diverging from reality.  Reported results looked fabulous, as they were based on stacked project valuations that were in turn based on optimistic forecasts of dealmakers who had every incentive to be optimistic.  But at the same time many of the deals were crap – some just projects where core assumptions such as natural gas prices had not played out as expected but increasingly including dumb domestic merchant investments and even worse international projects.  Crap projects were being approved based on insanely optimistic forecasts that no one had an incentive to challenge. Eventually, in bankruptcy, outsiders would be staggered by how much of Enron’s investments were absolute money-losing garbage.  Enron’s strategy went awry almost from the beginning, but that fact was hidden by the bad measurement system and so Enron kept doubling down on worse and worse investments, with the inflated mark-to-forecast numbers convincing everyone, especially themselves, that they were brilliant.

At some point the divergence between mark-to-market project values and actual results could not be ignored, and with the refusal to mark project values down, some other alternative was needed.   The solution they found was via corporate weasel Andy Fastow, their CFO who created off-books entities to hide losses from bad merchant investments rather than mark the losses to market.  Because the bad deals created little cash, new borrowing was constantly required which again was dumped into off-books entities (which were made worse by Fastow’s gluttonous self-dealing). 

It is these deals that get most of the historic attention, but in my mind, the off-books fraud merely delayed (and magnified) the reckoning of an organization already set up for disaster by the incentives and measurement plan of mark-to-market accounting that Skilling put in place.

Double Standard

Jeff Skilling of Enron essentially sits in jail for being too publicly optimistic about his company's prospects in the face of a liquidity crisis  (despite popular perceptions, he was not convicted for accounting issues associated with off balance sheet entities).

I didn't follow the trial that closely, but my sense is that Skilling denied this charge.  But even if he had admitted it, it strikes me that he would have had an interesting case in his favor.  US securities law takes as an absolute core principle that relevant information must always be disclosed quickly and completely to both shareholders and potential shareholders alike.  It presumes that total openness is the best way to serve shareholders.

But in a short-term liquidity crisis, openness is the kiss of death.  As we have seen over the last 6 months, the merest hint that a liquidity crisis may exist at a company creates a real crisis, even if one did not exist before.  Liquidity crises are crises of confidence among short-term lenders, and the only way to fight such a crisis is to build confidence.  So what happens if the best way to serve shareholders is to keep silent about problems?  What if the best way to fulfill one's fiduciary responsibility to maintaining shareholder value is to be overly rosy in one's pronouncements during difficult times?

Fast forward to the Bear Stearn failure last year, from the Economist:

As recently as March 12th, Alan Schwartz, the chief executive of Bear Stearns, issued a statement responding to rumours that it was in trouble, saying that "we don't see any pressure on our liquidity, let alone a liquidity crisis." Two days later, only an emergency credit line arranged by the Federal Reserve was keeping the investment bank alive. (Meanwhile, as its share price tumbled on rumours of trouble on March 17th, Lehman Brothers issued a statement confirming that its "liquidity is very strong.")

And now, we hear that the Federal Government urged Bank of America's Kenneth Lewis to do exactly what Lay and Skilling were convicted of.

Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke and then-Treasury Department chief Henry Paulson pressured Bank of America Corp. to not discuss its increasingly troubled plan to buy Merrill Lynch & Co. -- a deal that later triggered a government bailout of BofA -- according to testimony by Kenneth Lewis, the bank's chief executive.

Mr. Lewis, testifying under oath before New York's attorney general in February, told prosecutors that he believed Messrs. Paulson and Bernanke were instructing him to keep silent about deepening financial difficulties at Merrill, the struggling brokerage giant. As part of his testimony, a transcript of which was reviewed by The Wall Street Journal, Mr. Lewis said the government wanted him to keep quiet while the two sides negotiated government funding to help BofA absorb Merrill and its huge losses.

Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke and then-Treasury Department chief Henry Paulson pressured Bank of America Corp. to not discuss its increasingly troubled plan to buy Merrill Lynch & Co. -- a deal that later triggered a government bailout of BofA -- according to testimony by Kenneth Lewis, the bank's chief executive.

Mr. Lewis, testifying under oath before New York's attorney general in February, told prosecutors that he believed Messrs. Paulson and Bernanke were instructing him to keep silent about deepening financial difficulties at Merrill, the struggling brokerage giant. As part of his testimony, a transcript of which was reviewed by The Wall Street Journal, Mr. Lewis said the government wanted him to keep quiet while the two sides negotiated government funding to help BofA absorb Merrill and its huge losses.

Many observers found it odd when Skilling was convicted of giving false information to shareholders but not for insider trading.  The implication, then, was that Skilling was guilty of lying to shareholders but not for personal gain.  Why then, people asked, did he do it?  It is becoming increasingly clear that putting on a happy face during an impending liquidity crisis is the only responsible approach for a leader to take.  Whether he goes to jail for it or gets rewarded by the Feds for it comes down to, what?  PR?

Update: In fact, one can argue that the Enron situation is more honorable than the BofA situation.  Enron management was trying to protect the value of Enron shareholders.  In the case of BofA, the feds demanded that BofA management hide information in order to complete a transaction that BofA shareholders might rightly oppose.

Prosecuting Those With Bad PR

CEO's of companies struggling on the brink of failure often make happy, confident public statements that all is well.  Is that a crime?

Well, it depends on how you look at it.  It comes down to a CEO's fiduciary responsibility to the company's investors, and how that is regulated for public companies.  We think of fibbing to inflate the company stock poorly serves investors, but what about when the company is facing a liquidity crisis?  Isn't public optimism in a liquidity crisis exactly what is needed to serve shareholder's interests?  Consider Treasury Secretary Paulson, and his near criminal declaration of a financial crisis, and the effect these ill-considered statements have had on the economy.

It is hard for me nowadays not to think about Jeff Skilling, who sits in jail for making what the jury thought to be overly optimistic public statements about the company's financial health  (I know you are thinking that he was put in jail for all that off balance sheet accounting and gimmickry, but in fact the prosecution never chose to bring these charges in the trial).  Even Skilling's jury, which was pretty clearly predisposed to convict, seemed to acknowledge that he did not make these statements for personal gain.

So why is Skilling in jail and not, say GM CEO Rick Wagoner?  Wagoner was making a lot of happy-face statements just a few months before his company acknowledged they were facing chapter 11 if Congress did not bail him out.  For extra credit, Wagoner told Congress $15 billion would be enough of a bailout, when he had to have been pretty confident it was not going to come close to cover the hole he faced.

Tom Kirkendall asks some of  the same questions, and looking at the cases he cites, it seems fairly clear that the difference between prosecuted and un-prosecuted CEO's has more to do with their like-ability, celebrity status, and general PR position than their specific actions.

Postscript: I have actually been thinking about the Enron bankruptcy a bit lately for another reason.  Remember that massive natural gas shortage we had when Enron went bankrupt?  Neither do I.  That's because chapter 11 is a pretty well-oiled process in this country.  Enron shareholders, bondholders, and management lost most their investment (and their jobs) but Enron's productive assets and skilled employees didn't disappear.  Enron's assets were bought by other companies who hopefully will employ them more profitably and productively than Enron had.

The same goes for GM.  We have a well-understood and proven process for taking a company like GM through bankruptcy.  However, we are instead replacing this well-understood and practiced process with a new process, called something like "Congressionally-managed restructuring funded with taxpayer dollars."  Does anyone really think this new process is better than the one we have?  Its only advantage, at least to some, is that it may preserve some management jobs, and shareholder and bondholder value, at the expense of taxpayers and any real effort for long-term reform of how GM's assets are managed.